Слайд 2
ECONOMIC GROWTH I:
CAPITAL ACCUMULATION
&
POPULATION GROWTH
8
Слайд 3
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
8-2 The Golden
Rule Level of Capital
8-3 Population Growth
Слайд 4
The Solow growth model shows how
saving,
population
growth,
technological progress
Level & Growth of output
A
f f e c t
Слайд 5
Income and poverty in the world
selected countries,
2010
Indonesia
Uruguay
Poland
Senegal
Kyrgyz Republic
Nigeria
Zambia
Panama
Mexico
Georgia
Peru
Слайд 6
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand
for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady
State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
The Supply in the Solow model is based on the PF:
Y = F(K, L).
Assumption:
the PF has constant returns to scale:
zY = F(zK, zL), for any positive number z.
If z = 1/L →
Y/L = F(K/L, 1).
Слайд 7
y = Y/L is output per worker
k
= K/L is capital per worker
f(k) = F(k,
1)
y = f(k)
MPK = f(k + 1) − f(k)
k is low →
the average worker has only a little capital →
an extra unit of capital is very useful and →
He produces a lot of additional output.
k is high →
the average worker has a lot of capital already, →
so an extra unit increases production only slightly.
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
Y/L = F(K/L, 1)
Слайд 8
The Production Function
The PF shows how the amount
of capital per worker k determines the amount of
output per worker y = f (k).
Слайд 9
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand
for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady
State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
Output per worker y is divided between consumption per worker c and investment per worker i:
y = c + i.
G - we can ignore here and NX – we assumed a closed economy.
The Solow model assumes that people
save a fraction s of their income
consume a fraction (1 − s).
We can express this idea with the following CF:
c = (1 − s)y,
0 < s (the saving rate) < 1
Gnt. policies can influence a nation’s s
What s is desirable ?
Слайд 10
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand
for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady
State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
Assamption:
We take the saving rate s as given.
To see what this CF implies for I,
we substitute (1 − s)y for c
in the national income accounts identity:
y = (1 − s)y + i =>
i = sy
s is the fraction of y devoted to i.
Слайд 11
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand
for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady
State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
The 2 main ingredients of the Solow model—
the PF and the CF.
For any given capital stock k,
y = f(k)
determines how much Y the economy produces, and
s (i = sy)
determines the allocation of that Y between C & I.
Слайд 12
8-1 The Accumulation of Capital
The Supply and Demand
for Goods
Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady
State
Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example
How Saving Affects Growth
The capital stock (CS) is a key determinant of output,
its changes can lead to economic growth.
2 forces influence the CS.
Investment is expenditure on new plant and equipment, and it causes the CS to rise.
Depreciation is the wearing out of old capital, and it causes the CS to fall.
Investment per worker i = sy
We can express i as a function of the CS per worker:
i = sf(k).
This equation relates the existing CS k to the
accumulation of new capital i.
Слайд 13
Output, Consumption, and Investment
The saving rate s determines
the allocation of output between C & I.
For
any level of capital k,
output is f (k), investment is sf(k), and consumption is f (k) -sf(k).
Слайд 14
Depreciation is a constant fraction of the CS
wears out every year. Depreciation is therefore proportional to
the capital stock.
δ = the rate of depreciation
= the fraction of the capital stock that wears out each period
Слайд 15
Capital accumulation
Change in capital stock = investment – depreciation
Δk
= i – δk
Since
i = sf(k) , this becomes:
Δk = s f(k) – δk
The basic idea: Investment increases the capital stock, depreciation reduces it.
Слайд 16
The equation of motion for k
The Solow model’s
central equation
Determines behavior of capital over time…
…which, in turn,
determines behavior of
all of the other endogenous variables
because they all depend on k.
E.g.,
income per person: y = f(k)
consumption per person: c = (1–s) f(k)
Δk = s f(k) – δk
Слайд 17
The steady state
If investment is just enough to
cover depreciation
[sf(k) = δk ],
then capital per
worker will remain constant:
Δk = 0.
This occurs at one value of k, denoted k*,
called the steady state capital stock.
Δk = s f(k) – δk
Слайд 19
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
Слайд 20
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
Слайд 21
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
δk
k2
Слайд 22
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
δk
k2
Слайд 23
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
Слайд 24
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
δk
k2
k3
Слайд 25
Moving toward the steady state
Δk = sf(k) −
δk
k3
Summary:
As long as k < k*, investment will exceed
depreciation,
and k will continue to grow toward k*.
Слайд 26
Now you try:
Draw the Solow model diagram,
labeling
the steady state k*.
On the horizontal axis, pick
a value greater than k* for the economy’s initial capital stock. Label it k1.
Show what happens to k over time.
Does k move toward the steady state or
away from it?
Слайд 27
A numerical example
Production function (aggregate):
To derive the per-worker
production function, divide through by L:
Then substitute y =
Y/L and k = K/L to get
Слайд 28
A numerical example, cont.
Assume:
s = 0.3
δ= 0.1
initial value
of k = 4.0
Слайд 29
Approaching the steady state:
A numerical example
Year
k y c i k
k
1 4.000 2.000 1.400 0.600 0.400 0.200
2 4.200 2.049 1.435 0.615 0.420 0.195
3 4.395 2.096 1.467 0.629 0.440 0.189
4 4.584 2.141 1.499 0.642 0.458 0.184
…
10 5.602 2.367 1.657 0.710 0.560 0.150
…
25 7.351 2.706 1.894 0.812 0.732 0.080
…
100 8.962 2.994 2.096 0.898 0.896 0.002
…
9.000 3.000 2.100 0.900 0.900 0.000
Слайд 30
Exercise: Solve for the steady state
Continue to assume
s = 0.3, δ = 0.1, and y
= k 1/2
Use the equation of motion
Δk = s f(k) − δk
to solve for the steady-state values of k, y, and c.
Слайд 32
An increase in the saving rate
An increase in
the saving rate raises investment…
…causing k to grow toward
a new steady state:
Слайд 33
Prediction:
Higher s ⇒ higher k*.
And since
y = f(k) ,
higher k* ⇒ higher y*
.
Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher rates of saving and investment
will have higher levels of capital and income per worker in the long run.
Слайд 34
International evidence on investment rates and income per
person
100
1,000
10,000
100,000
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
Investment as percentage of output
(average 1960-2000)
Income per
person
in
2000
(log scale)
Слайд 35
The Golden Rule: Introduction
Different values of s lead
to different steady states.
How do we know which
is the “best” steady state?
The “best” steady state has the highest possible
consumption per person: c* = (1–s) f(k*).
An increase in s
leads to higher k* and y*, which raises c*
reduces consumption’s share of income (1–s),
which lowers c*.
So, how do we find the s and k* that maximize c*?
Слайд 36
The Golden Rule capital stock
the Golden Rule level
of capital,
the steady state value of k
that
maximizes consumption.
To find it, first express c* in terms of k*:
c* = y* − i*
= f (k*) − i*
= f (k*) − δk*
In the steady state: i* = δk* because Δk = 0.
Слайд 37
Then, graph
f(k*) and δk*,
look for the
point where
the gap between them is biggest.
The
Golden Rule capital stock
Слайд 38
The Golden Rule capital stock
c* = f(k*) −
δk*
is biggest where the slope of the production function
equals
the slope of the depreciation line:
steady-state capital per
worker, k*
MPK = δ
Слайд 39
The transition to the
Golden Rule steady state
The
economy does NOT have a tendency to move toward
the Golden Rule steady state.
Achieving the Golden Rule requires that policymakers adjust s.
This adjustment leads to a new steady state with higher consumption.
But what happens to consumption
during the transition to the Golden Rule?
Слайд 40
Starting with too much capital
then increasing c* requires
a fall in s.
In the transition to the
Golden Rule, consumption is higher at all points in time.
t0
c
i
y
Слайд 41
Starting with too little capital
then increasing c* requires
an
increase in s.
Future generations
enjoy higher consumption,
but the current
one experiences
an initial drop
in consumption.
time
t0
c
i
y
Слайд 42
Population growth
Assume that the population (and labor force)
grow at rate n. (n is exogenous.)
EX: Suppose
L = 1,000 in year 1 and the population is growing at 2% per year (n = 0.02).
Then ΔL = n L = 0.02 × 1,000 = 20,
so L = 1,020 in year 2.
Слайд 43
Break-even investment
(δ + n)k = break-even investment,
the
amount of investment necessary
to keep k constant.
Break-even
investment includes:
δ k to replace capital as it wears out
n k to equip new workers with capital
(Otherwise, k would fall as the existing capital stock would be spread more thinly over a larger population of workers.)
Слайд 44
The equation of motion for k
With population growth,
the equation of motion for k is
Δk = s
f(k) − (δ + n) k
Слайд 45
The Solow model diagram
Δk = s f(k) −
(δ +n)k
Слайд 46
The impact of population growth
Investment, break-even investment
Capital per
worker, k
(δ +n1) k
k1*
An increase in n
causes an increase in break-even investment,
leading to a lower steady-state level of k.
Слайд 47
Prediction:
Higher n ⇒ lower k*.
And since
y = f(k) ,
lower k* ⇒ lower y*.
Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with higher population growth rates will have lower levels of capital and income per worker in the long run.
Слайд 48
International evidence on population growth and income per
person
100
1,000
10,000
100,000
0
1
2
3
4
5
Population Growth
(percent per year; average 1960-2000)
Income
per Person
in 2000
(log scale)
Слайд 49
The Golden Rule with population growth
To find the
Golden Rule capital stock,
express c* in terms of
k*:
c* = y* − i*
= f (k* ) − (δ + n) k*
c* is maximized when
MPK = δ + n
or equivalently,
MPK − δ = n
In the Golden
Rule steady state,
the marginal product
of capital net of depreciation equals the population
growth rate.
Слайд 50
Alternative perspectives on population growth
The Malthusian Model (1798)
Predicts
population growth will outstrip the Earth’s ability to produce
food, leading to the impoverishment of humanity.
Since Malthus, world population has increased sixfold, yet living standards are higher than ever.
Malthus omitted the effects of technological progress.
Слайд 51
Alternative perspectives on population growth
The Kremerian Model (1993)
Posits
that population growth contributes to economic growth.
More people
= more geniuses, scientists & engineers, so faster technological progress.
Evidence, from very long historical periods:
As world pop. growth rate increased, so did rate of growth in living standards
Historically, regions with larger populations have enjoyed faster growth.
Слайд 52
Chapter Summary
1. The Solow growth model shows that, in
the long run, a country’s standard of living depends
positively
on its saving rate
negatively on its population growth rate
2. An increase in the saving rate leads to
higher output in the long run
faster growth temporarily
but not faster steady state growth.
CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I
slide